This is another look at the idea I put forth
here, that - contra the standard economic idea that consumption depends on wealth - I believe that consumption depends on income. It's worth stressing that wealth and income are not independent variables. Wealth is the accumulation of unspent income plus returns generated on that wealth over time. Is it proper to say that wealth is a stock, and income is a flow?
I believe the evidence very strongly indicates that consumption - also a flow - is tied tightly and directly to income. This does not mean that wealth cannot play a part in consumption decisions. People make all kinds of decisions about all kinds of things, for all kinds of reasons. But consumption decisions are constrained, and there is no reason why they can't be constrained in more than one way.
I think the idea that consumption depends primarily on wealth is intuitively weak because consumption is aggregated over the population, while wealth is concentrated in a small segment of that population. A person with little or no wealth will spend the next dollar meeting some unsatisfied need, while the person with lots of wealth has the option of devoting it to rent-seeking or accumulation in an off-shore shelter.
According to data now more than a decade old, the richest 1% of households owned 38% of all the wealth; the top 5% owned over half, and the top 20% owned over 80% of the wealth. The trend towards rising inequality started in the mid 70's.
A couple of proxies for wealth are home and common stock ownership. Excluding home-ownership, the wealth concentration is even more extreme, with the top 1% owning 50% of the non-home wealth. It's difficult to determine the actual amount of stock ownership in private hands. A number
arrived at by elimination leaves 36% among households, non-profits, endowments and hedge funds. Therefore, realistically, the bottom 99% of individuals share about 18% of all stocks with those other institutions. At the bottom end, the lowest 20% have either no wealth, or negative net worth.
People at the low end live close to subsistence. People in the middle live pay check to pay check. For the vast majority of the population, the next marginal dollar has a high probability of being used as a consumption expense.
That is my narrative to support the idea that consumption must necessarily be strongly dependent on income. Now, let's look at some data, through 2009, from the
U.S. Census Bureau, Table 678. The first graph shows Disposible Income (green) and personal Consumption Expenditures (red) back to 1929.
A careful look suggests a narrative about this relationship. First, consider the depression years. From 1932 to '34, consumption averaged 99% of disposable income. People had needs, and used their limited incomes to satisfy them, as best they could. Then, during WW II, with rationing and other constraints, saving was forced, and consumption was artificially low. Consumption reached an all-time low of 73.3% of Disposable Income in 1944. Since shortly after WW II, changes in Disposable Income and Consumption have been in virtual lock-step. I've put lines in a contrasting color connecting selected points in the Disposable Income curve, and dropped parallel lines for the same years onto the Consumption curve. Since 1951, very wiggle in Income corresponds to a wiggle in Consumption.
Here is a scattergram of the two subject variables, with a best-fit straight line provided by Excel.
As has been pointed out to me, correlation is not causation. But - when one can construct a rational narrative that explains the data, the two series display absolutely congruous motion over several decades, and R^2 is over 0.99, I'm willing to go out on a limb and say the burden of proof is on the denialists.
Here is a look at Consumption as a percentage of Disposable Income, since 1951.
I've expanded the Y-axis. In a view of the entire 0 to 100% scale, the post-1950 line barely wiggles. Over a span of 6 decades, Personal Consumption has averaged 90.1% of Disposable Income, with a standard deviation of 2.12%.
The data points, average, and an envelope one Std Dev above and below the average are all displayed on the graph. Despite having two clearly defined and opposite tending trends, this is still a well behaved data set, with 39 of 58 (67%) of the points within the envelope.
The two minima are in 1982 and 1984, and the bottom trend lines converge in 1982, so that is a reasonable time to define as the break point. This also suggests a narrative. During the post WW II golden age, typical wage earners moved incrementally above the subsistence level. This gave them the opportunity to save a little bit. Since 1982, as wages stagnated, it became necessary to devote a higher percentage to Consumption. Sure enough, savings grew through the mid 70's, and have dropped dramatically since 1982, as this FRED graph demonstrates.
I won't say that Consumption Spending is solely dependent on Income. But I will say that it is strongly, and even predominantly, dependent on income. Wealth might enter into the decision for those who actually have some, but they are in the minority and have few needs that can be satisfied by the next dollar of consumption.
My conclusion is that the best solution to the aggregate demand shortfall problem is to put money into the hands of the people who will actually spend it, and that the best way to do that is to give them jobs. As stop-gaps, various relief and welfare programs also have their place. This is the rational for fiscal stimulus. Federal spending programs provide real jobs for real people, and they will spend their earnings. Arguing about whether this is hole-filling or pump-priming strikes me as being just about as important as arguing about how many angels can dance on a pin head.
Update: Cross-posted at
Angry Bear