This is illustrated in Graph 1.
Graph 1 CARC vs Std Dev 1954-78, With Points Reallocated
The red dots are data points from 1954 through Q1 '62. The yellow dots are from Q1 '64 on. The blue dots are the three low Std Dev points from 1957, and the pink dots represent the transitions in and out of the 1957 blue-dot data, and the tumble down in Std Dev from Q2 '62 to Q4 ''63. The original blue trend line is retained for comparison. Note that removing these three blue and 8 transitional data points from the pre-1964 data set causes the negative correlation of that period to completely evaporate.
This might seem a bit arbitrary; but now we can observe a more tightly packed red data set, and the behavior of the pink data points does seem to be unusual. The string of high side outliers in the yellow data set occurs in 1971-2, and is associated with the 1970-71 recession.
This piqued my curiosity, so I took a look at the bigger picture - all 253 quarterly data points from Q1 1950 through Q1 2013, shown in Graph 2.
Graph 2 - CARC vs Std Dev 1950 to 2012
I see the great majority of these points clustering or stringing out along imaginary upward sloping lines that suggest coherent data subsets, and a relatively small number of points [39, or 15.4% of the total] where the data is in transition between sets.
I parsed it out as shown in graph 3.
Graph 3 - CARC vs Std Dev 1950 to 2012 - Parsed Data
The data points are color coded to correspond with the straight lines that best fit each subset of data, describing 5 distinct realms. Equations for the lines and R^2 values are also presented in corresponding colors.
The 39 light green dots represent the lowest Std Dev to CARC relationship. The 72 dark green dots represent a slightly higher relationship. These two subset occur across all decades from the 60's on in times of stable NGDP growth, i.e times outside of recessions. There are 41 blue points, representing a medium-high relationship. These occur when the economy is either in or coming out of a recession. The 53 yellow points represent a high Std Dev to CARC relationship. This has occurred during especially severe recessions, or when recessions repeat within the 12 quarter data kernel. The 8 red dots at the top of the graph are ultra-high. They demonstrate the severe economic instability of the early post WW II years. Four of these subsets exhibit extremely high R^2 values, above 0.91; and the fifth [yellow] is quite respectable at 0.74. The 39 pink dots occur in discrete short periods when Std Dev rises or falls sharply.
This is an unusual way of looking at GDP data, but I feel pretty good about it, because the linear subsets sort themselves out quite reasonably, and to my eye do not look contrived. Also, the data points of each subset generally follow the trend lines, in either clusters or strings, for several consecutive quarters. These subsets are trend stationary along the entire time span of the FRED data set, irrespective of inflation or disinflation; high or low levels of NGDP growth; and whether CARC is rising or falling. This suggests that the relationship between CARC and Std Dev is not random. Rather, it is deterministic, and also quantized. I'm reminded of the chart of nested Phillip's curves Noah Smith posted, and the quantization of electron energy levels diagram shown here.
To draw an analogy, recessions provide the activation energy to boost the Std Dev from a low level trend line to a higher level trend line. When the recession ends, the Std Dev naturally decays down to a lower level.
To bring this back into the real world, Graph 4 shows the 12 period CARC average from 1950 to 2013, with the CARC data points color coded to correspond with graph 2.
Graph 4 - CARC Color Coded to match Graph 2
The color coding is indicative of the economic conditions as described for Graph 3. Note that each of these data sets is coherent, irrespective of the inflationary environment or the long trend NGDP growth level. It is the presence or absence of recessions that mainly determines the realm in which the Std Dev of CARC resides. Outside of recessions, the data resides along one of the green lines. When not following any of these lines, the CARC - Std Dev relationship is transitional, moving into and out of recessions.
What strikes me is that I simply eyeballed straight lines through this scatter of data as an exercise in curiosity, and it wound up making some sort of coherent sense. Each of the realms associated with the best fit lines is trend stationary in a way that is robust across time and varying economic conditions.
But NGDP growth, per se, tells you absolutely nothing about either the rate of inflation nor the Std Dev realm. So - the big question in my mind is this: how can NGDP targeting be expected to lead to controlled, relatively stable economic growth at any desired level, unless you can also control not only the underlying rate of inflation, but also which Standard Deviation realm you end up in?
For anyone who's curious, Graph 5 shows the CARC - Std Dev scatter, color coded this time by decade.
Graph 5 - CARC vs Std Dev by Decades
Red - 1950-59
Yellow - 1960-69
Light Blue - 1970-79
Purple - 1980-89
Orange - 1990-99
Green - 2000-09
Blue - 2010-13
Note three things. 1) As the data moves across time, when it gets to one of the realms described by Graph 3, it tends to linger there. These trend stationary realms have real traction. 2) Transitions generally take a short, quick route to the next trend line. 3) Since 1980 there has been a choppy but relentless migration to lower and lower NGDP growth. We are now stuck in the worst recovery on record, and the lowest growth period ever to occur outside of a recession. In fact, NDGP growth is now lower than that which has occurred within most recessions.
Whether fiscal policy, monetary policy, trade policy or something else I can't think of is to blame, this is, to borrow a phrase from my seven-year-old granddaughter Emily, a "total epic fail" of economic policy. It is grim on a scale unprecedented in the post WW II period.
2 comments:
Or to put it more briefly: WASF.
SIGH!
The important point, though, is that the entire idea of NGDP targeting is a sham.
It doesn't address inflation in any way I'm aware of, totally ignores the act that NGDP tells you nothing about income distribution, and now I think we can say that there is no way to correlate NGDP growth at any level with volatility.
Cheers!
JzB
Post a Comment